jamesrmaclean | Sectionalism has been used in two closely related senses. One refers to a regional division, such as a group of states (i.e., divisions of a country) or provinces. The other refers to a division of society
that makes its money a certain way. The two concepts are closely
related, since sectional divisions of a country usually correspond to
reliable generalizations as to the source of each section's wealth.
Sectional interests often come into conflict, but typically the
parties involved are aware of the unlikelihood of a victory in open
struggle. There are a few historical cases in which sectionalism has
erupted into civil war;
this site takes the position that most allegedly "ethnic" or
"sectarian" conflicts are actually sectional conflicts caused by a
breakdown of sectional comity.
In the United States
The obvious example of a sectional conflict is the one that raged between the CSA and the northern states, or residual of the United States. Here, the most compelling difference between the two sections was that one relied heavily on slavery,
while the other found slavery threatening. More schematically, one
relied on the endless expansion of exactly the same system (gangs of slaves
working on freshly cleared land to produce the same cash crop in
ever-greater volume); the other was a diversified economy which ranged
from semi-subsistence farming to large-scale industrial enterprise. The
"sections" of the Union advanced fundamentally incompatible claims to
the vast amounts of territory that the USA either bought, seized, or
divided. Even when significant numbers of actual slaves were not
present (Kansas) or never could be (as was alleged with New Mexico and
Arizona), the dividing sectional principle was too basic to be resolved
peacefully. A crucial claim of the Southern partisans was that,
regardless of the merits of slavery, restrictions on slavery in the
territories (or, for that matter, the states themselves) represented a
violation of the equal protection of Southern slaveowners per se. Under
slavery, captive humans in servitude were capital,
but if slavery was illegal in a territory—or even in a neighboring
state—then one type of capitalist was not allowed in. And while the
great majority of Whites in the South owned few or no slaves, slaveowners were the politically decisive class.[1]
The North also had sectional interests, ones that bound the East with the West: the industrial system that united them depended on a much costlier system of public works, public education, and governmental
regulation. Slavery typically faired best in cases where law
enforcement was cheap and crude, and dominated entirely by slaveowners.
In industrial systems where there was rapid innovation and complex
networks of contracts, patents, public services, and technical
competition from established foreign companies. The most obvious
example was tariff policy and public improvements, but additional
issues concerned the nationalization of state debts, federal control
over banking and securities, and land policy.[2]
The fundamental difference was that the survival of the Northern
economy required a reliable foundation for rapid technological
innovation and implementation, while the South was highly sensitive to
cost. Moreover, the South was threatened by the relative rise of the
North as a political counterweight.
After the Civil War, the sectional interests shifted somewhat. The
South was still hypersensitive to costs, such as taxes and rising wages;
the North was still responding to rapid changes in technology and high
fixed costs for plants. But Southern planters could no longer control
the entire political structure as easily as before; there were now rival
bases of political power (between 1868 and 1898, African American
voters were such a base). At the same time, the interests in the North
who had demanded a strong government hand in the economy to ensure the
creation of power industrial corporations, by the end of Reconstruction,
were increasingly at swords points with the burgeoning populism of
their workforce and small farmers. Tariffs were high, but labor was
militant and populist democracy was corrupt; while the robber barons had tended
to champion a strong government leading up to the Grant Administration,
and bribed the one they had on a prodigious scale, they were faced with
a sinkhole of malfeasance.[3] In response, they favored the creation of the firm as surrogate to the state: the modern industrial corporation. This was to be the ultimate counterforce to social democracy
in the United States, and it meshed with the sectional interests of the
planters. Not only could planters form a permanent coalition with the
corporate elites to defeat social democratic legislation at the federal
level, they could also continue to use their rising economic hegemony
as a unifying enemy for poor Southern Whites. The South remained
totally dominated by one political party (the Democrats) until the late
1960's, but in Southern states the party actually housed multiple rival
factions; the politically conservative faction sided with Northern Republicans, while the populist faction sided with the (weak) Northern Democrats.
Since the time of the Civil Rights Movement,
sectional alignments have evolved further; they still have a decidedly
economic orientation, with the Democratic Party corresponding to
industry and the Republican Party corresponding to resource extraction,
farming, financial services, and business management. Casual observers usually assume the Democratic Party is liberal (and hypocritical),
while the Republican Party is conservative (and sincere). In reality,
both parties are conservative, but oriented towards different sectional
interests. The Democratic Party favors public education, public works,
and a robust regulatory regime; the Republican Party sometimes claims it
does also, but its position towards all three is hectoring and
unsupportive. The Republican Party, in turn, favors minimal government
role in the economy, and a compensatory maximal role of the state in
enforcing market incentives. These are compatible with the "night
watchman state" popular among extractive industries such as factory farming,
mining, and fossil fuels; and the punitive enforcement of incentives
popular with financial services and business management (as a separate
political section).
1 comments:
Greetings! Very helpful advice in this particular post! It is the little changes that make the largest changes. Many thanks for sharing! [url=http://www.cwstudio.it/fr/maillot-equipe-de-france-pas-cher/]Maillot Equipe de France[/url] Greetings! Very useful advice within this post! It is the little changes which will make the most important changes. Thanks for sharing! [url=http://www.masciabrunelli.it/fr/maillotpsg/]maillot psg 2014[/url] I every time emailed this blog post page to all my associates, for the reason that if like to read it then my links will too.
Post a Comment