ineteconomics | Buchanan, a 1940 graduate of Middle Tennessee State University who
later attended the University of Chicago for graduate study, started out
as a conventional public finance economist. But he grew frustrated by
the way in which economic theorists ignored the political process.
Buchanan began working on a description of power that started out as a
critique of how institutions functioned in the relatively liberal 1950s
and ‘60s, a time when economist John Maynard Keynes’s ideas about the
need for government intervention in markets to protect people from flaws
so clearly demonstrated in the Great Depression held sway. Buchanan,
MacLean notes, was incensed at what he saw as a move toward socialism
and deeply suspicious of any form of state action that channels
resources to the public. Why should the increasingly powerful federal
government be able to force the wealthy to pay for goods and programs
that served ordinary citizens and the poor?
In thinking about how people make political decisions and choices,
Buchanan concluded that you could only understand them as individuals
seeking personal advantage. In an interview cited by MacLean, the
economist observed that in the 1950s Americans commonly assumed that
elected officials wanted to act in the public interest. Buchanan
vehemently disagreed — that was a belief he wanted, as he put it, to
“tear down.” His ideas developed into a theory that came to be known as
“public choice.”
Buchanan’s view of human nature was distinctly dismal. Adam Smith saw
human beings as self-interested and hungry for personal power and
material comfort, but he also acknowledged social instincts like
compassion and fairness. Buchanan, in contrast, insisted that people
were primarily driven by venal self-interest. Crediting people with
altruism or a desire to serve others was “romantic” fantasy: politicians
and government workers were out for themselves, and so, for that
matter, were teachers, doctors, and civil rights activists. They wanted
to control others and wrest away their resources: “Each person seeks
mastery over a world of slaves,” he wrote in his 1975 book, The Limits of Liberty.
Does that sound like your kindergarten teacher? It did to Buchanan.
The people who needed protection were property owners, and their
rights could only be secured though constitutional limits to prevent the
majority of voters from encroaching on them, an idea Buchanan lays out
in works like Property as a Guarantor of Liberty (1993).
MacLean observes that Buchanan saw society as a cutthroat realm of
makers (entrepreneurs) constantly under siege by takers (everybody else)
His own language was often more stark, warning the alleged “prey” of
“parasites” and “predators” out to fleece them.
In 1965 the economist launched a center dedicated to his theories at
the University of Virginia, which later relocated to George Mason
University. MacLean describes how he trained thinkers to push back
against the Brown v. Board of Education decision to desegregate
America’s public schools and to challenge the constitutional
perspectives and federal policy that enabled it. She notes that he took
care to use economic and political precepts, rather than overtly racial
arguments, to make his case, which nonetheless gave cover to racists who
knew that spelling out their prejudices would alienate the country.
All the while, a ghost hovered in the background — that of John C.
Calhoun of South Carolina, senator and seventh vice president of the
United States.
Calhoun was an intellectual and political powerhouse in the South
from the 1820s until his death in 1850, expending his formidable energy
to defend slavery. Calhoun, called the “Marx of the Master Class” by
historian Richard Hofstadter, saw himself and his fellow southern
oligarchs as victims of the majority. Therefore, as MacLean explains, he
sought to create “constitutional gadgets” to constrict the operations
of government.
Economists Tyler Cowen and Alexander Tabarrok, both of George Mason University, have noted the two men’s affinities, heralding
Calhoun “a precursor of modern public choice theory” who “anticipates”
Buchanan’s thinking. MacLean observes that both focused on how democracy
constrains property owners and aimed for ways to restrict the latitude
of voters. She argues that unlike even the most property-friendly
founders Alexander Hamilton and James Madison, Buchanan wanted a private
governing elite of corporate power that was wholly released from public
accountability.
Suppressing voting, changing legislative processes so that a normal
majority could no longer prevail, sowing public distrust of government
institutions— all these were tactics toward the goal. But the Holy Grail
was the Constitution: alter it and you could increase and secure the
power of the wealthy in a way that no politician could ever challenge.
Gravy Train to Oligarchy
MacLean explains that Virginia’s white elite and the pro-corporate
president of the University of Virginia, Colgate Darden, who had married
into the DuPont family, found Buchanan’s ideas to be spot on. In
nurturing a new intelligentsia to commit to his values, Buchanan stated
that he needed a “gravy train,” and with backers like Charles Koch and
conservative foundations like the Scaife Family Charitable Trusts,
others hopped aboard. Money, Buchanan knew, can be a persuasive tool in
academia. His circle of influence began to widen.
MacLean observes that the Virginia school, as Buchanan’s brand of
economic and political thinking is known, is a kind of cousin to the
better-known, market-oriented Chicago and Austrian schools — proponents
of all three were members of the Mont Pelerin Society, an international
neoliberal organization which included Milton Friedman and Friedrich
Hayek. But the Virginia school’s focus and career missions were
distinct. In an interview with the Institute for New Economic Thinking
(INET), MacLean described Friedman and Buchanan as yin and yang:
“Friedman was this genial, personable character who loved to be in
the limelight and made a sunny case for the free market and the freedom
to choose and so forth. Buchanan was the dark side of this: he thought,
ok, fine, they can make a case for the free market, but everybody knows
that free markets have externalities and other problems. So he wanted to
keep people from believing that government could be the alternative to
those problems.”
0 comments:
Post a Comment